In January, when the central bank of the United States also left its rate steady following a 25 basis point rate increase in December last year - the first rate hike since July 2006 - the Fed also referred to the global economy in explaining its decision, saying it was closely monitoring the impact on labor markets and inflation from global economic and financial developments.
But unlike the unanimous decision at the Jan. 27 meeting of the 10-member Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), Esther George, president of the Kansas City Fed, today voted to raise the rate by 25 points to 0.75 percent.
Reflecting the worsening in the outlook for the global economy in the last few months, the Fed lowered its forecasts for economic growth, inflation and the path for the fed funds rate.
The fed funds rate is now seen by the FOMC members and Fed presidents as averaging 0.9 percent this year, sharply down from the December forecast of 1.4 percent, implying that the Fed may only raise the rate another two times this year compared with the previous forecast of four rate hikes.
For 2017 the fed funds rate is forecast to average 1.9 percent, down from the previous forecast of 2.4 percent, and in 2018 3.0 percent, down from 3.3 percent.
Since the January meeting, the FOMC said economic activity in the U.S. has continued to expand at "a moderate pace despite the global economic and financial developments of recent months," with household spending rising, the housing sector improving further while business investment and exports have been soft.
In comparison with its previous statement, the Fed's policy-making body again noted the improvement in household spending but changed its view on investment by businesses to "soft" from "rising", a likely reaction by companies to the uncertain global outlook.
The Fed trimmed its forecast for economic growth this year to 2.2 percent from December's forecast of 2.4 percent and the 2017 forecast to 2.1 percent from 2.2 percent. The forecast for 2018 was unchanged at 2.0 percent.
In the fourth quarter of 2015, U.S. Gross Domestic Product grew by an annual rate of 1.9 percent, the lowest quarterly growth rate since the first quarter of 2014, and down from 2.1 percent in the third quarter of last year.
As in January, the FOMC acknowledged the improving labor market while inflation continues to run below its 2.0 percent objective, mainly due to lower energy prices and non-energy imports.
The forecast for the Fed's preferred inflation gauge, personal consumption expenditure, was lowered to 1.2 percent for this year from 1.6 percent seen in December, but then left unchanged for 2017 and 2018 at 1.9 and 2.0 percent, respectively.
The headline inflation rate in the U.S. fell to 1.0 percent in February from January’s 1.4 percent as energy costs again fell. But excluding the cost of energy and food, core inflation accelerated for the fourth consecutive month to 2.3 percent, the highest rate since May 2012. The PCE inflation gauge rose to 1.3 percent in January, up from 0.7 percent in December.
The FOMC also confirmed its view of recent months that it expects economic conditions to "evolve in a manner that will warrant only gradual increases in the federal funds rate," though the actual path of the rate will depend on the changes to the economic outlook.
The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System issued the following statement:
"Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in January suggests that economic activity has been expanding at a moderate pace despite the global economic and financial developments of recent months. Household spending has been increasing at a moderate rate, and the housing sector has improved further; however, business fixed investment and net exports have been soft. A range of recent indicators, including strong job gains, points to additional strengthening of the labor market. Inflation picked up in recent months; however, it continued to run below the Committee's 2 percent longer-run objective, partly reflecting declines in energy prices and in prices of non-energy imports. Market-based measures of inflation compensation remain low; survey-based measures of longer-term inflation expectations are little changed, on balance, in recent months.
Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum employment and price stability. The Committee currently expects that, with gradual adjustments in the stance of monetary policy, economic activity will expand at a moderate pace and labor market indicators will continue to strengthen. However, global economic and financial developments continue to pose risks. Inflation is expected to remain low in the near term, in part because of earlier declines in energy prices, but to rise to 2 percent over the medium term as the transitory effects of declines in energy and import prices dissipate and the labor market strengthens further. The Committee continues to monitor inflation developments closely.
Against this backdrop, the Committee decided to maintain the target range for the federal funds rate at 1/4 to 1/2 percent. The stance of monetary policy remains accommodative, thereby supporting further improvement in labor market conditions and a return to 2 percent inflation.
In determining the timing and size of future adjustments to the target range for the federal funds rate, the Committee will assess realized and expected economic conditions relative to its objectives of maximum employment and 2 percent inflation. This assessment will take into account a wide range of information, including measures of labor market conditions, indicators of inflation pressures and inflation expectations, and readings on financial and international developments. In light of the current shortfall of inflation from 2 percent, the Committee will carefully monitor actual and expected progress toward its inflation goal. The Committee expects that economic conditions will evolve in a manner that will warrant only gradual increases in the federal funds rate; the federal funds rate is likely to remain, for some time, below levels that are expected to prevail in the longer run. However, the actual path of the federal funds rate will depend on the economic outlook as informed by incoming data.
The Committee is maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments from its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency mortgage-backed securities and of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at auction, and it anticipates doing so until normalization of the level of the federal funds rate is well under way. This policy, by keeping the Committee's holdings of longer-term securities at sizable levels, should help maintain accommodative financial conditions.
Voting for the FOMC monetary policy action were: Janet L. Yellen, Chair; William C. Dudley, Vice Chairman; Lael Brainard; James Bullard; Stanley Fischer; Loretta J. Mester; Jerome H. Powell; Eric Rosengren; and Daniel K. Tarullo. Voting against the action was Esther L. George, who preferred at this meeting to raise the target range for the federal funds rate to 1/2 to 3/4 percent."
Following is a transcript of Chair Janet Yellen's press conference:
www.CentralBankNews.infoFollowing is a transcript of Chair Janet Yellen's press conference:
CHAIR YELLEN: Good afternoon. Today, the Federal Open Market Committee
decided to maintain the target range for the federal funds rate at 1/4 to 1/2 percent. Our decision
to keep this accommodative policy stance reflects both our assessment of the economic outlook
and the risks associated with that outlook. The Committee’s baseline expectations for economic
activity, the labor market, and inflation have not changed much since December: With
appropriate monetary policy, we continue to expect moderate economic growth, further labor
market improvement, and a return of inflation to our 2 percent objective in two to three years.
However, global economic and financial developments continue to pose risks. Against this
backdrop, the Committee judged it prudent to maintain the current policy stance at today’s
meeting. I will come back to our policy decision momentarily, but first let me review recent
economic developments and the outlook.
The labor market continues to strengthen. Over the most recent three months, job gains averaged nearly 230,000 per month, similar to the pace experienced over the past year. The unemployment rate was 4.9 percent in the first two months of the year, about in line with the median of FOMC participants’ estimates of its longer-run normal level. A broader measure of unemployment that includes individuals who want and are available to work but have not actively searched recently and people who are working part time but would rather work full time has continued to improve. Of note, the labor force participation rate has turned up noticeably since the fall, with more people working or actively looking for work as the prospects for finding jobs have improved. But there is still room for improvement: Involuntary part-time employment remains somewhat elevated, and wage growth has yet to show a sustained pickup.
The labor market continues to strengthen. Over the most recent three months, job gains averaged nearly 230,000 per month, similar to the pace experienced over the past year. The unemployment rate was 4.9 percent in the first two months of the year, about in line with the median of FOMC participants’ estimates of its longer-run normal level. A broader measure of unemployment that includes individuals who want and are available to work but have not actively searched recently and people who are working part time but would rather work full time has continued to improve. Of note, the labor force participation rate has turned up noticeably since the fall, with more people working or actively looking for work as the prospects for finding jobs have improved. But there is still room for improvement: Involuntary part-time employment remains somewhat elevated, and wage growth has yet to show a sustained pickup.
The improvement in employment conditions so far this year has occurred as economic
growth appears to have picked up from the modest pace seen in the fourth quarter of last year.
Household spending is expanding at a moderate rate, supported by continued job gains and
increases in inflation-adjusted incomes. In contrast, business investment has been weak, in part
reflecting further reductions in oil drilling as a result of low oil prices. Net exports also remain
soft as a consequence of subdued foreign growth and the earlier appreciation of the dollar.
Looking ahead, the Committee expects that, with gradual adjustments in the stance of monetary
policy, economic activity will continue to expand at a moderate pace and labor market indicators
will continue to strengthen.
Ongoing economic growth and additional strengthening in labor market conditions are important factors underpinning the inflation outlook. Overall consumer price inflation--as measured by the price index for personal consumption expenditures--stepped up to 1-1/4 percent over the 12 months ending in January, as the sharp decline in energy prices around the end of 2014 dropped out of the year-over-year figures. Core inflation (which excludes energy and food prices) has also picked up, although it remains to be seen if this firming will be sustained. In particular, the earlier declines in energy prices and appreciation of the dollar could well continue to weigh on overall consumer prices. But once these transitory influences fade, and as the labor market strengthens further, the Committee expects inflation to rise to 2 percent over the next two to three years.
The Committee’s inflation outlook rests importantly on its judgment that longer-run inflation expectations remain reasonably well anchored. However, the stability of longer-run inflation expectations cannot be taken for granted. Survey-based measures of longer-run inflation expectations are little changed, on balance, in recent months although some remain near historically low levels. Market-based measures of inflation compensation also remain low. Movements in these indicators reflect many factors and therefore may not provide an accurate reading on changes in the inflation expectations that are most relevant for wage and price setting. Nonetheless, our statement continues to emphasize that, in considering future policy decisions, we will carefully monitor actual and expected progress toward our inflation goal.
Ongoing economic growth and additional strengthening in labor market conditions are important factors underpinning the inflation outlook. Overall consumer price inflation--as measured by the price index for personal consumption expenditures--stepped up to 1-1/4 percent over the 12 months ending in January, as the sharp decline in energy prices around the end of 2014 dropped out of the year-over-year figures. Core inflation (which excludes energy and food prices) has also picked up, although it remains to be seen if this firming will be sustained. In particular, the earlier declines in energy prices and appreciation of the dollar could well continue to weigh on overall consumer prices. But once these transitory influences fade, and as the labor market strengthens further, the Committee expects inflation to rise to 2 percent over the next two to three years.
The Committee’s inflation outlook rests importantly on its judgment that longer-run inflation expectations remain reasonably well anchored. However, the stability of longer-run inflation expectations cannot be taken for granted. Survey-based measures of longer-run inflation expectations are little changed, on balance, in recent months although some remain near historically low levels. Market-based measures of inflation compensation also remain low. Movements in these indicators reflect many factors and therefore may not provide an accurate reading on changes in the inflation expectations that are most relevant for wage and price setting. Nonetheless, our statement continues to emphasize that, in considering future policy decisions, we will carefully monitor actual and expected progress toward our inflation goal.
This general assessment of the outlook is reflected in the individual economic projections
submitted for this meeting by FOMC participants. As always, each participant’s projections are
conditioned on his or her own view of appropriate monetary policy, which, in turn, depends on
each person’s assessment of the multitude of factors that shape the outlook. Participants’
projections for growth of inflation-adjusted gross domestic product (GDP) are just a touch lower
than the projections made in conjunction with the December FOMC meeting. The median
growth projection edges down from 2.2 percent this year to 2 percent in 2018, in line with its
estimated longer-run rate. The median projection for the unemployment rate falls from 4.7 at the
end of this year to 4.5 percent at the end of 2018, somewhat below the median assessment of the
longer-run normal unemployment rate. The median path of the unemployment rate is a little
lower than in December, in part reflecting a slightly lower median estimate of the longer-run
normal unemployment rate. Finally, with the transitory factors holding down inflation expected
to abate and labor market conditions anticipated to strengthen further, the median inflation
projection rises from 1.2 percent this year to 1.9 percent next year and 2 percent in 2018. The
median inflation projection for this year is a little lower than in December, but thereafter the
median projections are unchanged.
Since the turn of the year, concerns about global economic prospects have led to increased financial market volatility and somewhat tighter financial conditions in the United States, although financial conditions have improved notably more recently. In addition, economic growth abroad appears to be running at a somewhat softer pace than previously expected. These unanticipated developments, however, have not resulted in material changes to the Committee’s baseline outlook. One reason for this is that market expectations for the path of policy interest rates have moved down, and the accompanying decline in longer-term interest rates should help cushion any possible adverse effects on domestic economic activity. Indeed, while stock prices have fallen slightly since the December meeting and spreads of investment- grade corporate bond yields over those on comparable-maturity Treasury securities have risen, mortgage rates and corporate borrowing costs have moved lower. Of course, the Committee will continue to monitor these developments closely and will adjust the stance of monetary policy as needed to foster our goals of maximum employment and 2 percent inflation.
As we indicated in our statement, the Committee expects that economic conditions will
evolve in a manner that will warrant only gradual increases in the federal funds rate. The federal
funds rate is likely to remain, for some time, below levels that are expected to prevail in the
longer run. This expectation is consistent with the view that the neutral nominal federal funds
rate--defined as the value of the federal funds rate that would be neither expansionary nor contractionary if the economy was operating near potential--is currently low by historical
standards and is likely to rise only gradually over time. The low level of the neutral federal
funds rate may be partially attributable to a range of persistent economic headwinds that weigh
on aggregate demand, including developments abroad, a subdued pace of household formation,
and meager productivity growth. There is considerable uncertainty regarding the evolution of
the neutral funds rate over time. However, if these headwinds abate, as we expect, the neutral
federal funds rate should gradually move higher as well.
I would like to underscore, however, that the participants’ projections for the federal
funds rate, including the median path, are not a “plan” for future policy. Policy is not on a pre-
set course. These forecasts represent participants’ individual assessments of what appropriate
policy would be given each person’s own current projections of the most likely outcomes for
economic growth, employment, inflation, and other factors. However, considerable uncertainty
attaches to each participant’s forecasts of economic outcomes. Hence, their assessments of appropriate policy are also uncertain and will change in response to adjustments to the economic
outlook and associated risks, as was the case between December and now.
STEVE LIESMAN. Steve Liesman, CNBC. Madam Chair, as you know, inflation has
gone up the last two months. We had another strong jobs report, the tracking forecast for GDP
have returned to 2 percent, and yet the Fed stands pat while it's in a process of what it said it
launched in December was a process of normalization. So I have two questions about this. Does
the Fed have a credibility problem, in the sense that it says it will do one thing under certain
conditions but doesn't end up doing it? And then frankly, if the current conditions are not
sufficient for the Fed to raise rates, well, what would those conditions ever look like?
Now, I guess, you asked me also what would we need to see to continue raising rates.
And I think it's worth pointing out here that the Committee, most participants do continue to
envision that if economic developments unfold as they expect, that further increases in the
federal funds rate will prove appropriate over time--most participants anticipate that--and that the
pace will be gradual. As I emphasized, most empirical work attempting to assess what the
equilibrium level of the fed funds rate is a level that would be neither expansionary nor contractionary is--those assessments are quite low at this time. So, there is accommodation in the
stance of policy. And we do expect over time that neutral rate to move up but, you know, we're
not positive what rate--what the pace of change of that will be over time. But given that the
economy is now close to our maximum employment objective, you know, hopefully inflation is
moving up by mentioned--as you mentioned, recent readings on inflation have moved up. There
may be some--you know, I want to warn that there may be some transitory factors that are
influencing that. But certainly, our projections are for gradual increase in inflation. And the
Committee, at least most participants, continued to expect that if we follow along this course,
that some further adjustments in the federal funds rate will be appropriate but gradual.
CHAIR YELLEN. So, I want to make clear that our inflation objective is 2 percent and
we're projecting a move back to 2 percent, and we are not trying to engineer an overshoot of
inflation, not to compensate for past undershoots, so 2 percent is our objective. But it is a
symmetric objective, and we certainly don't seek to overshoot our objective. But some
undershoots and overshoots are part of how the economy operates and our tolerance for those is
symmetric with respect to under and overshoots. We did take note in the statement of the fact
that inflation is picked up in recent months. I see some of that is having to do with unusually
high inflation readings in categories that tend to be quite volatile without very much significance for inflation over time. So, I'm wary and haven't yet concluded that we have seen any significant
uptick that will be lasting in, for example, in core inflation. But we note--the Committee notes, as
it did in December, that we continue to monitor development trends and developments closely.
And that would include both the fact that recent inflation readings have been on the high side.
And, as I mentioned, on the other side, that readings on measures of inflation compensation and
some survey measures have been on the low side. So in that sense, there are risks around the
inflation forecast in both directions.
CHAIR YELLEN. So, there has been a slight downgrading of the assessment of
economic growth for this year. But nevertheless, growth is expected to run in somewhat an
excess of potential, so that the labor market is expected to continue to tighten. And by the end of
the year, even edge below levels that--of the unemployment rate that are estimated to be longer
in the normal run. And inflation is expected to gradually move back to 2 percent over time. We
still have, weighing on inflation, the influence of earlier declines in energy prices, and a
prolonged effect from the appreciation of the dollar. But we do expect those transitory influences
to fade. And with continuing improvement in the labor market, I think we'll see upward pressure
on inflation. And in that context, the Committee sees it appropriate to--if things unfold in that
way--to have some further increases in the federal funds rate. It remains accommodative, as I indicated in December, the Committee indicated in December, we want inflation to go back to 2
percent. But we also want to be careful not to see some significant overshoots, so that we would
get behind the curve and potentially be faced with a need to tighten in a very rapid fashion later
in a way that could undermine the sustainability of the employment gains we've had. But we do
see some continued tightening in monetary policy to be appropriate in that event.
Since the turn of the year, concerns about global economic prospects have led to increased financial market volatility and somewhat tighter financial conditions in the United States, although financial conditions have improved notably more recently. In addition, economic growth abroad appears to be running at a somewhat softer pace than previously expected. These unanticipated developments, however, have not resulted in material changes to the Committee’s baseline outlook. One reason for this is that market expectations for the path of policy interest rates have moved down, and the accompanying decline in longer-term interest rates should help cushion any possible adverse effects on domestic economic activity. Indeed, while stock prices have fallen slightly since the December meeting and spreads of investment- grade corporate bond yields over those on comparable-maturity Treasury securities have risen, mortgage rates and corporate borrowing costs have moved lower. Of course, the Committee will continue to monitor these developments closely and will adjust the stance of monetary policy as needed to foster our goals of maximum employment and 2 percent inflation.
Returning to monetary policy, as I noted earlier, the Committee decided to maintain its
target range for the federal funds rate. This decision partly reflects the implications for the U.S.
economy of the global economic and financial developments I just mentioned. In addition,
proceeding cautiously in removing policy accommodation at this time will allow us to verify that
the labor market is continuing to strengthen despite the risks from abroad. Such caution is
appropriate given that short-term interest rates are still near zero, which means that monetary
policy has greater scope to respond to upside than to downside changes in the outlook.
This view is implicitly reflected in participants’ projections of appropriate monetary
policy. The median projection for the federal funds rate rises only gradually to 0.9 percent late
this year and 1.9 percent next year. As the factors restraining economic growth are projected to
fade further over time, the median rate rises to 3 percent by the end of 2018, close to its longer-
run normal level. Compared with the projections made in December, the median path is about
1/2 percentage point lower this year and next; the median longer-run normal federal funds rate
has been revised down as well. In other words, most Committee participants now expect that
achieving economic outcomes similar to those anticipated in December will likely require a
somewhat lower path for policy interest rates than foreseen at that time.
Also, it is important to note that the Committee makes its decisions on a meeting-by-
meeting basis and does not and need not decide on a likely future path for the federal funds rate.
Indeed, the future path of policy is necessarily uncertain because the economy will surely evolve
in unexpected ways. As we note in our statement, the actual path of the federal funds rate will
depend on the economic outlook as informed by incoming data.
Finally, the Committee will continue its policy of reinvesting proceeds from maturing Treasury securities and principal payments from agency debt and mortgage-backed securities. As highlighted in our policy statement, we anticipate continuing this policy until normalization of the level of the federal funds rate is well under way. Maintaining our sizable holdings of longer-term securities should help maintain accommodative financial conditions and should reduce the risk that we might have to lower the federal funds rate to zero in the event of a future large adverse shock.
Thank you, and I’ll be happy to take your questions.
Finally, the Committee will continue its policy of reinvesting proceeds from maturing Treasury securities and principal payments from agency debt and mortgage-backed securities. As highlighted in our policy statement, we anticipate continuing this policy until normalization of the level of the federal funds rate is well under way. Maintaining our sizable holdings of longer-term securities should help maintain accommodative financial conditions and should reduce the risk that we might have to lower the federal funds rate to zero in the event of a future large adverse shock.
Thank you, and I’ll be happy to take your questions.
CHAIR YELLEN. Well, let me start with the question of the Fed's credibility. And you
used the word promises in connection with that. And as I tried to emphasize in my opening
statement, the paths that the participants project for the federal funds rate and how it will evolve
are not a pre-set plan or commitment or promise of the Committee. Indeed, they are not even--
the median should not be interpreted as a Committee-endorsed forecast. And there's a lot of
uncertainty around each participant's projection. And they will evolve, those assessments of
appropriate policy are completely contingent on each participant's forecast of the economy and
how economic events will unfold. And they are, of course, uncertain, and you should fully
expect that forecast for the appropriate path of policy on the part of all participants will evolve
over time as shocks, positive or negative, hit the economy that alter those forecasts. So, you have
seen a shift this time in most participants' assessments of the appropriate path for policy. And as
I tried to indicate, I think that largely reflects a somewhat slower projected path for global
growth, for growth in the global economy outside the United States, and for some tightening in
credit conditions in the form of an increase in spreads. And those changes in financial conditions
and in the path of the global economy have induced changes in the assessment of individual
participants in what path is appropriate to achieve our objectives. So, that's what you see. That's
what you see.
SAM FLEMING. Sam Fleming from the Financial Times. Can I just follow up on this
inflation point? Because the numbers have been ticking up as you said, somewhat, at least. And
we're also, as you said, also at a point where we have a quite close to full employment. Is there a
risk that we're heading for an overshoot in inflation, and is there, given the greater symmetry, the
Fed has been flagging up, in terms of its inflation target, a greater tolerance for a modest
overshoot, especially given the long period of undershoots that we've been through?
LINDSAY DUNSMUIR. Hi, Lindsay Dunsmuir with Reuters. Your statement did note
that, as you're saying, that inflation has picked up in recent months and you do still see it going
back to 2 percent over the medium term. Yet policymakers have downgraded GDP growth
forecast for this year and one of the inflation measures. So, that to me would indicate a
weakening economic environment. And I'm wondering how, in that environment, you justify the
possibility of two rate hikes this year.
PETER BARNES. Hi, Peter Barnes with FOX Business. Could you get a little bit more
specific about the global and economic financial developments that continue to pose risks to the
U.S. economy? You did mention a strong dollar there just a second ago and slowing global
growth. But are you specifically concerned about, for example, China, the emerging markets, and
the EU? Could you expand on the risks?
CHAIR YELLEN. So there has been, by many forecasters, slight downgrading of forecast of global growth in, over the coming, several years. The IMF has slightly downgraded their forecast, and other international agencies have as well. Chinese growth hasn’t proven a great surprise. We've anticipated that it would slow over time, and it seems to be slowing as well. Japanese growth in the fourth quarter was negative and that was something of a surprise. And with respect to the Euro area, recent indicators suggest perhaps slightly weaker growth. So there's been a number of emerging markets. As you know, we're suffering under the weight of declines in oil prices that are affecting their economic activity. Our neighbors both to the north and south, Canada and Mexico, are feeling the impacts of lower oil prices on their growth. So, our projection for global growth, for those reasons, is slightly lower--not dramatically lower, but enough lower to make some difference to our forecast. And as I indicated, I think that’s part of the reason, along with the associated increase we've seen in some spreads that are involved in, enter into corporate borrowing rates, and can affect investment decisions, it's a reason to think that a slightly lower path for the federal funds rate will be appropriate to achieve our objectives. And so, what you see here is a virtually unchanged path of economic projections and a slightly more accommodative path that most participants are writing down for what's necessary to achieve that.
CHAIR YELLEN. So let me start with the impact of oil prices on consumer spending. I
have to say it's very difficult, when you look at patterns of consumer spending, to--there are
many factors that influence it. And to definitively say that lower oil prices have not boosted
consumer spending, I'm not sure we can really arrive at that conclusion in any rigorous way. The typical, the average household in the United States with oil prices, where they are now, is
probably benefiting around $1,000 a year. And some very detailed microdata that I've seen on
household spending patterns suggest that there may be a linkage you would expect from reduced
bill, you know, reduced amounts that people pay at the pump to other spending like eating out
for restaurant meals and other things. But the aggregate data, you know, is not as strong as it--
and spending is not as strong as it could be, given the decline. And of course, on the other side,
we are--and maybe that it will take a while and it's something that we'll slowly strengthen over
time if oil prices stay low--on the other side of course, we have seen a marked decline in drilling
activity, which is a depressed investment spending, and of course very substantial layoffs in the
energy sector.
With respect to impact of oil prices on inflation and what would happen if they move up, the Committee has generally tended to look through movements in oil prices, whether they were on the upside or on the downside, viewing it as a factor that should have a transitory influence. When I say that, what I mean is that if oil prices move up during the time that it's moving up, it raises inflation. But they don't need to move down again to their previous levels for that influence to disappear. They only need to stabilize at a higher level. And similarly, oil prices have obviously moved down a great deal over the last year. And we're not expecting them to move back to their previous levels, but to stabilize at some level. They're obviously volatile. But as they stabilize, the influence will move out of both headline--of headline inflation. And that's what you see in the forecasts of participants. So, if oil prices were to increase to 50, I mean, that would probably slightly move up our expected path for core inflation, maybe speed how rapidly we would move back to 2 percent. But I wouldn't think that that would be something alone that would have great policy significance.
MARTY CRUTSINGER. Marty Crutsinger, Associated Press. You said in--the policy statement in December said that the risk to the outlook were balanced and you raised rates. That phrasing disappeared then in January and March. Could you talk a little bit about--but in your comments today, you seemed to be indicating that not that much has changed. Could you help us understand what needs to happen to get back to balanced? And is that the language we need to look for to see the next rate hike?
But I think it is important to note a couple of things. First of all, the U.S. economy has
been very resilient in recent months in the face of shocks. And we highlighted that right at the
beginning of our statement, where we said that economic activity has been expanding at a
moderate pace despite the global economic and financial developments of recent months. And
that, that is important that the U.S. economy continues to do well. Second, I would say that while
global developments do pose some downside risks, the risks are not all one-sided. A number of
countries--including China, the Euro area, the Bank of Japan--have taken measures to stimulate
the economy. So there is also upside risk to the economic outlook. And in addition, oil prices
have rebounded from their lows and that eases concerns about the financial condition of some
energy firms and the stresses facing some oil-producing economies. And at the same time, low oil prices continue to boost household purchasing power. So there are risks, we're attentive to
them. We have not described them as unbalanced to the out--to the downside. And they're two-
sided. One can identify both upside and downside risks here.
CHAIR YELLEN. So there has been, by many forecasters, slight downgrading of forecast of global growth in, over the coming, several years. The IMF has slightly downgraded their forecast, and other international agencies have as well. Chinese growth hasn’t proven a great surprise. We've anticipated that it would slow over time, and it seems to be slowing as well. Japanese growth in the fourth quarter was negative and that was something of a surprise. And with respect to the Euro area, recent indicators suggest perhaps slightly weaker growth. So there's been a number of emerging markets. As you know, we're suffering under the weight of declines in oil prices that are affecting their economic activity. Our neighbors both to the north and south, Canada and Mexico, are feeling the impacts of lower oil prices on their growth. So, our projection for global growth, for those reasons, is slightly lower--not dramatically lower, but enough lower to make some difference to our forecast. And as I indicated, I think that’s part of the reason, along with the associated increase we've seen in some spreads that are involved in, enter into corporate borrowing rates, and can affect investment decisions, it's a reason to think that a slightly lower path for the federal funds rate will be appropriate to achieve our objectives. And so, what you see here is a virtually unchanged path of economic projections and a slightly more accommodative path that most participants are writing down for what's necessary to achieve that.
KATE DAVIDSON. Thank you. Kate Davidson from the Wall Street Journal. Madam
Chair, you've emphasized repeatedly that every meeting of the FOMC is a live meeting. You
have a meeting next month. Is it possible that you could get enough information between now
and then to, you know, get you comfortable with raising rates again in April? And what would
you need to see?
CHAIR YELLEN. So, I will say again that every meeting is a live meeting. April remains a live meeting and we will be tracking incoming data. It's a slightly shorter period. We have six weeks, but there will be additional data on the labor market and on various factors that pertain to inflation. So that's, you know, that's--that is certainly a large possibility.
STEVEN MUFSON. Two questions. The oil, lower oil prices--I think a lot of people expected to lead to more consumer spending. What do you--how do you see and how do you explain that that hasn't worked out as well--the way a lot of people expected? And also, if oil prices were to pop back up to, say, $50, not that high by some standards, what impact would that have on inflation? Would you be paying more attention to the overall inflation rate? Or would you then look to the core rate to determine what the Fed’s policies would be?
CHAIR YELLEN. So, I will say again that every meeting is a live meeting. April remains a live meeting and we will be tracking incoming data. It's a slightly shorter period. We have six weeks, but there will be additional data on the labor market and on various factors that pertain to inflation. So that's, you know, that's--that is certainly a large possibility.
STEVEN MUFSON. Two questions. The oil, lower oil prices--I think a lot of people expected to lead to more consumer spending. What do you--how do you see and how do you explain that that hasn't worked out as well--the way a lot of people expected? And also, if oil prices were to pop back up to, say, $50, not that high by some standards, what impact would that have on inflation? Would you be paying more attention to the overall inflation rate? Or would you then look to the core rate to determine what the Fed’s policies would be?
With respect to impact of oil prices on inflation and what would happen if they move up, the Committee has generally tended to look through movements in oil prices, whether they were on the upside or on the downside, viewing it as a factor that should have a transitory influence. When I say that, what I mean is that if oil prices move up during the time that it's moving up, it raises inflation. But they don't need to move down again to their previous levels for that influence to disappear. They only need to stabilize at a higher level. And similarly, oil prices have obviously moved down a great deal over the last year. And we're not expecting them to move back to their previous levels, but to stabilize at some level. They're obviously volatile. But as they stabilize, the influence will move out of both headline--of headline inflation. And that's what you see in the forecasts of participants. So, if oil prices were to increase to 50, I mean, that would probably slightly move up our expected path for core inflation, maybe speed how rapidly we would move back to 2 percent. But I wouldn't think that that would be something alone that would have great policy significance.
MARTY CRUTSINGER. Marty Crutsinger, Associated Press. You said in--the policy statement in December said that the risk to the outlook were balanced and you raised rates. That phrasing disappeared then in January and March. Could you talk a little bit about--but in your comments today, you seemed to be indicating that not that much has changed. Could you help us understand what needs to happen to get back to balanced? And is that the language we need to look for to see the next rate hike?
CHAIR YELLEN. So, let me say that, in recent weeks, I think the Committee certainly
thinks that risks to the outlook have diminished. Nevertheless, we continue to see risks, which
we highlighted. Now, I would point out that we decided not to describe the balance of risks has
weighted to the downside. So the Committee did not reach that judgment. And there is no
collective judgment in this statement on whether the risks are balanced or not. My--we decline to
make a collective assessment. You know, my guess is that some participants see them as
balanced and some see them as weighted somewhat to the downside.
JIM PUZZANGHERA. Hi, Jim Puzzanghera with the L.A. Times. Wage growth thus far
has been disappointing. It's been very uneven. It was disappointing, the figures in the last
month's job's report. Why do you think that is and how important is sustained wage growth to
removing your wariness on inflation?
CHAIR YELLEN. So, I must say I do see broad-based improvement in the labor market. And I'm somewhat surprised that we're not seeing more of a pick-up in wage growth. But at least, and I have to say in anecdotal reports, we do hear quite a number of reports of firms facing wage pressures and even broad-based, slightly faster increases in wages--wage increases that they're granting. But in the aggregate data, one doesn't yet see any convincing evidence of a pick-up in wage growth. It's mainly isolated to certain sectors and occupations. So, I do think, consistent with the 2 percent inflation objective, that there is certainly scope for further increases in wages. The fact that we have not seen any broad-based pick-up is one of the factors that suggest to me that there is continued slack in the labor market. But I would expect wage growth to move up some.
PATRICK GILLESPIE. Patrick Gillespie with CNNMoney. Chair Yellen, numerous polls show, by CNN and others, show that the U.S. economy is American voters' number one concern right now, there's a lot of negative sentiment about the economy. Yet, unemployment is low, job gains have been pretty good for the past year, and consumer confidence has picked up. Why do you think there is such disparity between the progress--between the economy and its progress, and how voters feel? And my second question is how does any negative sentiment about the economy factor into your economic outlook and the decisions you make on monetary policy? Thank you.
CHRIS CONDON. Thank you, [inaudible]. Chair Yellen, there seems to be some
growing sentiment that even if the direct economic ties between the US and other economies is
still relatively modest, that the impact through financial markets and exchange rates has become
more robust. And because of that, it's becoming more difficult or will become more difficult for
the Fed to diverge from other major central banks with its benchmark interest rate. Would you generally agree with that sentiment? Why or why not? And regarding briefly, the second if I
may, in your mind, does it undermine in any way the standing of the Federal Reserve as a non-
partisan institution when one of its sitting governors contributes to the campaign of a national
political figure? Thank you.
So, I wouldn't want to endorse the notion if, you know, that you're suggesting that our
policy is in some way crippled by the fact that there are these inter-linkages. That’s simply how
the global financial system works. We--this is one reason we meet frequently with other
economic policymakers in other countries, exchange notes about how we see economic
developments evolve, and try to keep one another apprised of economic developments and likely
policy responses. Your second question concerned the political contributions. So, I want to start by saying
that I've been involved for many years in the Federal Reserve System, and we are a nonpartisan,
independent institution devoted to pursuing our congressionally-mandated objectives, and I have
never seen political views in any way influence the policy judgments that are made inside the
Federal Reserve. I want to say that emphatically.
CHAIR YELLEN. So, I mean, the path of rate increases maybe slightly reflects the
modest decline in estimates of the longer-run normal unemployment rate. That I would say
reflects, for those who brought it down, an estimate of greater slack in the labor market. The fed funds rate projection is not just that; it's also, as I mentioned, a reflection of shifts and other
views of that, for example, the likely pace of global growth that affects what we need, as a policy
path, to achieve our objectives. But the slow pace of wage growth, the fact that part-time
employment for economic reasons, and voluntary part-time employment remains high. We have
seen an upward move in labor force participation, which is heartening and suggests that there
was scope there for further improvement in the labor market. My guess is that those things
influence individuals who wrote down the slightly lower number for the longer-run
unemployment rate.
With respect to the nomination for vice chair of supervision, that's a question that I think
you need to pose to the White House. I, you know, would say that we are doing a very good job
on supervision, and, you know, we are very focused on and devote a great deal of time to that
issue. So, really it's the nomination question is one for the White House.
JOHN HELTMAN. Thank you, Madam Chair. John Heltman with American Banker. The president last week expressed concern about what he termed cynicism on both sides of the aisle concerning progress made since the crisis to reform the banking sector and the financial sector more generally. Do you share that concern about kind of public attitudes that either not enough has been done, or what has been done has not been effective in changing the regulatory landscape in banking? Just what are your thoughts?
A month or so ago, we came out with a rule, so-called TLAC rule, that would require the
largest firms to hold a substantial buffer of long-term debt that, in the event that they were to fail,
could be bailed in to protect the taxpayer from having to bear any burden in terms of injecting
capital into the firms that would provide loss absorption in that event. And working jointly, closely with the FDIC, firms have made a great deal of progress with their living wills. We’re in
the process of evaluating the most recent submissions. And working with the FDIC, I think,
potential techniques that could be used in the event of a failure of a significant financial
institution, we've also made a lot of progress there.
KAREN MRACEK. Karen Mracek, with Market News International. In the SEP today,
the unemployment rate forecast for future years, for 2017, 2018 was marked down without
changes to inflation, and there seems to be growing debate about the relationship between
higher--lower unemployment and higher inflation. What is your view about the strength of this
relationship, the Phillips curve? And how does that view weigh in to just how much actual
inflation versus anticipation--anticipated inflation you'll need to see? CHAIR YELLEN. OK, so that was a complicated question, and there--let me start with
the Phillips curve. So, the Phillips curve posits that there is a relationship between the degree of
slack in the labor market and inflation, and it is an empirical relationship that, while not
absolutely tight, has been a consistent relationship over time, and I believe that relationship still
holds. But the impact of shifts in the unemployment rate on inflation should not be overstated.
The Phillips curve has become, according to most estimates, quite flat in the sense that
movements and unemployment have only a modest impact on inflation. So, we shouldn't
overblow how large that is.
Inflation compensation is measured in financial markets, also embodies a variety of risk
premia and liquidity premia. And so, it's also, we monitor those closely and discuss them in the
statement in paragraph one. But again, there's not a straight read on what's happening to the expectations that influence wage and price-setting. But this model continues to at least influence
my own thinking, and it certainly is a factor that I and at least some of my colleagues are
incorporating in these projections.
But look, if we found ourselves in the unlikely situation where we needed to add
accommodation, we have a range of tools, and we know from the things we did in the past that
we have a number of options with respect to the maturity, for example, of our portfolio, with respect to asset purchases or forward guidance that remain available to us that are tools we could
turn to in the unlikely event that we need to add accommodation. So, negative rates is not
something that we're actively considering.
CHAIR YELLEN. So, I must say I do see broad-based improvement in the labor market. And I'm somewhat surprised that we're not seeing more of a pick-up in wage growth. But at least, and I have to say in anecdotal reports, we do hear quite a number of reports of firms facing wage pressures and even broad-based, slightly faster increases in wages--wage increases that they're granting. But in the aggregate data, one doesn't yet see any convincing evidence of a pick-up in wage growth. It's mainly isolated to certain sectors and occupations. So, I do think, consistent with the 2 percent inflation objective, that there is certainly scope for further increases in wages. The fact that we have not seen any broad-based pick-up is one of the factors that suggest to me that there is continued slack in the labor market. But I would expect wage growth to move up some.
PATRICK GILLESPIE. Patrick Gillespie with CNNMoney. Chair Yellen, numerous polls show, by CNN and others, show that the U.S. economy is American voters' number one concern right now, there's a lot of negative sentiment about the economy. Yet, unemployment is low, job gains have been pretty good for the past year, and consumer confidence has picked up. Why do you think there is such disparity between the progress--between the economy and its progress, and how voters feel? And my second question is how does any negative sentiment about the economy factor into your economic outlook and the decisions you make on monetary policy? Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Well, let me start with your second question if I might. So, in trying to
judge the outlook for the economy, we do look at measures pertaining to consumer sentiment,
and they are in solid territory. Household balance sheets are much improved. Gains in inflation-
adjusted disposable income are running at a healthy pace. As I mentioned, households have
benefited pretty significantly from lower oil prices, and measures of consumer sentiment do
reflect--do reflect that. So, they're not at low levels. And really, the labor market, I think, has
improved a great deal, and every demographic group that, you know, we tracked regularly has
seen improvement in their labor market situation, perhaps not all equally but almost all
demographic groups have seen improvement. So, I think it's right to say the economy is
improving, and most groups are seeing benefits.
That said, we know that inequality has been rising in the United States over many years, not just the last several but going back to the mid-80s. There has been downward pressure on real wage groups--on real wage gains for groups, particularly those that are less skilled and educated, and those longer-term trends that may be associated with a number of factors--technological change and globalization--have been a concern for many, many years, and that may be part of what you're, we're seeing expressed.
That said, we know that inequality has been rising in the United States over many years, not just the last several but going back to the mid-80s. There has been downward pressure on real wage groups--on real wage gains for groups, particularly those that are less skilled and educated, and those longer-term trends that may be associated with a number of factors--technological change and globalization--have been a concern for many, many years, and that may be part of what you're, we're seeing expressed.
CHAIR YELLEN. So, let me start with the question pertaining to exchange rates. We
have global capital markets. In a world with highly-integrated capital markets, monetary policy
actions in any country have affects, spillovers to other countries. That's true of our monetary
policy, and it's true of other countries' monetary policies. In part, that shows up through
movements in exchange rates, and those movements are a factor that any country needs to take
into account in deciding what is the appropriate stance of monetary policy. So, the fact that there
are these linkages is an important factor in designing a monetary policy.
But it does not mean that monetary--US monetary policy is somehow constrained in a way that makes it impossible for our monetary policy to diverge from policies abroad. There are many periods when monetary policies in different countries have moved in different directions, and, you know, the United States has been growing more strongly and had better success in the labor market than many other advanced countries. And at this point, it's natural that there should be some divergence in our monetary policies. Movements in exchange rates partly reflect that.
But it does not mean that monetary--US monetary policy is somehow constrained in a way that makes it impossible for our monetary policy to diverge from policies abroad. There are many periods when monetary policies in different countries have moved in different directions, and, you know, the United States has been growing more strongly and had better success in the labor market than many other advanced countries. And at this point, it's natural that there should be some divergence in our monetary policies. Movements in exchange rates partly reflect that.
The political activities of governors, participants, government employees are governed by
the Hatch Act. We are all subject to that, and the Hatch Act does allow campaign contributions
to be made. It outlaws other forms of partisan activity. And I would say, within that, so with this
each--it's up to each individual to decide what is appropriate in their point of view. But the
Federal Reserve is not a partisan political organization.
BINYAMIN APPELBAUM. Binya Appelbaum, The New York Times. The policy, the projections--the new economic projections appear to reflect an increase in your estimate of the extent of labor market slack. You talked about one possible reason for that, which is the softness of wage growth. Are there other considerations that have led you to increase your estimate of how much slack there is in the labor market?
CHAIR YELLEN. So, I should point out that I think what you're talking about is the slight decline in the median estimate of the longer-run normal unemployment rate. Is that--is that what you're--
BINYAMIN APPELBAUM. [Inaudible] the rate increases combined with projections with relative respect to inflation.
BINYAMIN APPELBAUM. Binya Appelbaum, The New York Times. The policy, the projections--the new economic projections appear to reflect an increase in your estimate of the extent of labor market slack. You talked about one possible reason for that, which is the softness of wage growth. Are there other considerations that have led you to increase your estimate of how much slack there is in the labor market?
CHAIR YELLEN. So, I should point out that I think what you're talking about is the slight decline in the median estimate of the longer-run normal unemployment rate. Is that--is that what you're--
BINYAMIN APPELBAUM. [Inaudible] the rate increases combined with projections with relative respect to inflation.
NANCY MARSHALL-GENZLER. Nancy Marshall-Genzler from Marketplace. We've
heard a lot of talk today about President Obama's pick for the Supreme Court, but there are a
number of vacancies on the Fed Board of Governors. And there's a new position, the vice chair
for supervision, that the president hasn't even nominated anyone for. Would you like the
president to nominate someone for that position? And what effect are those vacancies having on
the Fed?
CHAIR YELLEN. Well, I think Congress intended for the Federal Reserve Board to have seven members, and that tends to bring on board people with a wide spectrum of views and experience and perspectives. I think that's valuable, and I would like to see the Senate move forward and consider these nominees so that we could operate with a full complement.
CHAIR YELLEN. Well, I think Congress intended for the Federal Reserve Board to have seven members, and that tends to bring on board people with a wide spectrum of views and experience and perspectives. I think that's valuable, and I would like to see the Senate move forward and consider these nominees so that we could operate with a full complement.
JOHN HELTMAN. Thank you, Madam Chair. John Heltman with American Banker. The president last week expressed concern about what he termed cynicism on both sides of the aisle concerning progress made since the crisis to reform the banking sector and the financial sector more generally. Do you share that concern about kind of public attitudes that either not enough has been done, or what has been done has not been effective in changing the regulatory landscape in banking? Just what are your thoughts?
CHAIR YELLEN. So, I feel a great deal has been done. We have been working at this for
a number of years, and I believe we have made very substantial progress. We have a much more
capital, higher-quality capital, liquidity in the banking system. Our supervision has--we've made
very meaningful changes for--in our supervision, for example. The stress tests--the stress test
methodology that we use routinely to evaluate the robustness of the capital positions and plans of
the largest institutions constitutes a quantum leap in terms of, I think, the quality of the
supervision we are providing, especially of the largest firms. So, we have finished writing most
of the Dodd-Frank rules. We’re working very hard on "too big to fail", which is of grave concern
to the American people.
In addition to having a financial system that is more robust and less likely to experience a failure, we've also worked very hard, continue to work on making sure we have the ability to resolve a firm if it were to fail in spite of having more capital and liquidity. And there, too, I think, we've made very substantial progress.
In addition to having a financial system that is more robust and less likely to experience a failure, we've also worked very hard, continue to work on making sure we have the ability to resolve a firm if it were to fail in spite of having more capital and liquidity. And there, too, I think, we've made very substantial progress.
I think I was at the meeting of financial regulators with the president when he made those
comments, and I understood that what he was trying to tell the American people that they should
understand there really has been very substantial progress, and that's something they should be
aware of.
JOHN HELTMAN. Sorry, but do you think that despite all that progress that there--why hasn't that message--why hasn't--why haven't these improvements made its way to the public? And perhaps, like, do you find that that is an obstacle either among people that you meet, people in the public or the representatives in Congress that maybe have this pervasive view that nothing has changed? Is that an obstacle? Is that a problem?
CHAIR YELLEN. Well, I think--I think it's our job as we make these improvements to explain what we're doing and to try to educate the public about what's happened, and they may not understand how much has changed. It's certainly part of my own responsibility to try to explain that to the American people.
JOHN HELTMAN. Sorry, but do you think that despite all that progress that there--why hasn't that message--why hasn't--why haven't these improvements made its way to the public? And perhaps, like, do you find that that is an obstacle either among people that you meet, people in the public or the representatives in Congress that maybe have this pervasive view that nothing has changed? Is that an obstacle? Is that a problem?
CHAIR YELLEN. Well, I think--I think it's our job as we make these improvements to explain what we're doing and to try to educate the public about what's happened, and they may not understand how much has changed. It's certainly part of my own responsibility to try to explain that to the American people.
In addition, the Phillips curve theory suggests that inflation expectations are also an
important driver of actual wage and price-setting decisions and inflation behavior, and I believe
there's also solid empirical evidence for that. And it's one of the reasons that I highlighted in my
statement, and we continue to highlight in the FOMC statement that we are tracking indicators of
the inflation expectations that matter to wage and price-setting.
Now, unfortunately, we don't have perfect measures of these things. We have survey measures. We know that household measures, even when households are asked about longer- term inflation--at longer-term inflation, they tend to move in response to salient changes in prices that they see every day. In particular, when gas prices go down, which is very noticeable to most households, you tend to see a view--you tend to see responses about long-term inflation marked down. So, that's kind of an over-response to something that's transitory. So, it's difficult to get a clear read from those survey measures.
Now, unfortunately, we don't have perfect measures of these things. We have survey measures. We know that household measures, even when households are asked about longer- term inflation--at longer-term inflation, they tend to move in response to salient changes in prices that they see every day. In particular, when gas prices go down, which is very noticeable to most households, you tend to see a view--you tend to see responses about long-term inflation marked down. So, that's kind of an over-response to something that's transitory. So, it's difficult to get a clear read from those survey measures.
ERIC SCHATZKER. Eric Schatzker, Bloomberg Television, Madam Chair, thank you.
Notwithstanding what the dots tell us about rate expectations, has there been any discussion
among members of the Committee about the potential need for further stimulus? And even if
there hasn't been such a discussion yet, could you share with us what you have learned from the
reevaluation of negative interest rates, whether you consider negative interest rates effective,
how effective relative to quantitative easing, and whether the Committee would hypothetically
use them instead of or in conjunction with quantitative easing in the event that the economy
should warrant further stimulus?'
CHAIR YELLEN. OK, so, what I would like to make clear is that this is not actively a subject that we are considering or discussing. The Committee continues to feel that we are on a course where the economy is improving, and inflation is moving back up. And as I indicated, if events continue to unfold in that way, we are likely to gradually raise rates over time. Again, that's not fixed in stone. We'll watch how the economy behaves. We're prepared to respond if things transpire differently. But we are not spending time actively debating and considering things we could do for additional accommodation and certainly not actively considering negative rates. We are looking at the experience in other countries, and I guess I would judge they seem to have mixed effects, you know, some positive and some negative things.
CHAIR YELLEN. OK, so, what I would like to make clear is that this is not actively a subject that we are considering or discussing. The Committee continues to feel that we are on a course where the economy is improving, and inflation is moving back up. And as I indicated, if events continue to unfold in that way, we are likely to gradually raise rates over time. Again, that's not fixed in stone. We'll watch how the economy behaves. We're prepared to respond if things transpire differently. But we are not spending time actively debating and considering things we could do for additional accommodation and certainly not actively considering negative rates. We are looking at the experience in other countries, and I guess I would judge they seem to have mixed effects, you know, some positive and some negative things.
0 comments:
Post a Comment